Graduate Studies Blog
NANYANG EXECUTIVE MBA, NANYANG MBA, NANYANG PROFESSIONAL MBA & NANYANG FELLOWS MBA
TRUST AND VALUE CREATION
The 2008 Global Financial Crisis (GFC) is often cited as an example of a collapse of trust. At the time, former US Secretary of Labour Robert Reich noted in US News, “the fundamental problem isn’t lack of capital. It’s lack of trust. And without trust, Wall Street might as well fold up its fancy tents.”
The loss of trust during the GFC has even given birth to blockchain technology, with its main purpose to embed trust in commercial transactions.
Trust is invisible and fragile. Trust is also a vital and valuable asset for businesses. It is an expectation that a firm will perform actions that are beneficial, or at least not harmful, to its stakeholders, regardless of the ability to monitor those actions. Such an expectation takes time to earn, and it certainly cannot be forced.
A firm that is highly trusted by its stakeholders is likely to reap value from this precious asset. We will look at how this is achieved.
Explicit and implicit contracts
According to contract theory and the theory of the firm, we can view a firm as a nexus of implicit and explicit contracts between shareholders and other stakeholders. Each group of stakeholders supplies the firm with critical resources or efforts in exchange for claims outlined in explicit contracts and suggested in implicit contracts.
Take, for example, the employment contract between the firm and its employees. The explicit contract spells out the terms of employment, including job responsibilities, wages, leave entitlement, among others. At the same time, the implicit contract is an understanding between the firm and its employees, such as providing opportunities for employees to develop themselves for possible career progression, or the promise to retrain and redeploy them to new roles when their current roles no longer exist. These are often not part of any formal agreement.
When a large firm enters into a long-term contract with its supplier, it often requires the supplier to make fixed and intangible assets investments to fulfil the contractual obligation. The firm may endeavour to alleviate the supplier’s concerns of the firm reneging on the agreement after the supplier has made the required investment. It can do so by establishing mutual dependency via explicit contracts such as most-favoured-supplier clauses, exclusive territories, or patent pools. However, a large proportion of contracts are still implicit, for example, the promise to be fair if market conditions change or product changes.
When a customer buys an expensive branded durable such as a car or a bag, there is an implicit contract between the firm and the customer that the firm will continue to invest and build the brand image. When we buy “xiaolongbao” from Din Tai Fung, a can of Coca-Cola, or a Big Mac from McDonald’s, there is an implicit contract that we have with these firms. The implicit contract promises us a consistent quality and taste, or the “secret recipe”.
Unlike explicit contracts, implicit contracts are nebulous and have little legal standing. Firms can default on their implicit commitment without legal recourse from other stakeholders. As such, the value of implicit contracts depends on other stakeholders’ expectations about a firm honouring its commitments.
For firms that have a stronger reputation for keeping their commitments associated with the implicit contracts, stakeholders are likely to have stronger incentives to contribute resources and effort to the firm and accept less favourable explicit contracts than stakeholders of less trustworthy firms.
These theories suggest that the interests of shareholders and other stakeholders in a hightrust firm are in greater alignment than those of shareholders and other stakeholders in a low-trust firm. Hence, they are more likely to contribute to the firms’ superior long-term financial performance.
Does it pay to invest in trust?
The theoretical argument is intuitive and logical. But does it pay for a firm to invest and build trust with its stakeholders? Is there evidence that investing in trust can lead to better financial performance and valuation for the firm?
One of the challenges in establishing a causal relationship between the trust level and the firm’s financial performance is the measurement of trust.
Academia regards a firm’s corporate social responsibility (CSR) activities as a good measure of the trust level that a firm has with its stakeholders.
A World Business Council for Sustainable Development report on CSR by Holme and Watts in 2000 states that: “For any company, giving a high priority to CSR is no longer seen to represent an unproductive cost or resource burden, but, increasingly, as a means of enhancing reputation and credibility among stakeholders – something on which success or even survival may depend.”
In recent years, using a firm’s CSR activities as a measure of the firm’s trust level, several empirical studies show a causal relationship between the trust level with the firm’s financial performance. See box, “Does it Pay to Invest in Trust?”.
Trust and value creation
In summary, trust is a valuable and vital asset for firms. It enhances the value of implicit contracts embedded in a firm’s contracts with its customers, employees, suppliers, creditors, regulators, and other stakeholders.
The stakeholders of these high-trust firms are likely to have stronger incentives to contribute resources and effort to the firm and accept less favourable explicit contracts than stakeholders of less trustworthy firms. As such, these high-trust firms will enjoy better financial performance and higher valuation.
Firms should understand that high stakeholder trust is the bedrock of business success. Such trust can be built through CSR.
As Naill Fitzgerald, CEO and co-chairman of Unilever told The Guardian (2003), “Corporate social responsibility is a hard-edged business decision. Not because it is nice to do or because people are forcing us to do it…, but because it is good for our business…. More and more people are looking at companies and ask themselves if this is an organisation whose values they share. This is a hard-edged business issue.”
Professor Low Buen Sin is Professor of Finance and Associate Dean of China Programmes and Executive Education at the Nanyang Business School, Nanyang Technological University. He has deep industry experience and he has been actively involved in industry consultation and in-house executive training for major organizations in the public and private sectors. Prof Low is also a former council member of the Institute of Valuers and Appraisers, Singapore. |
This article first appeared in the Q2 2021 issue of the SID Directors Bulletin published by the Singapore Institute of Directors.
The Nanyang Executive MBA is a part-time 13-months programme that is designed for senior leaders aspiring to innovate and transform the way they lead. The programme aims to embrace the connection between business, technology, and innovation to deliver a relevant curriculum to business leaders to excel in global environments and adapt to each new wave of digital change.
Download the Nanyang Executive MBA brochure
Click here to learn more about the Nanyang Executive MBA programme or contact us at execmba@ntu.edu.sg.
You must be logged in to post a comment.